March
12,
2024
This
essay is in response to the October 2023 interview and discussion
between Prosocial World and Evolution Institute founder, and renowned
evolutionary biologist, David Sloan Wilson, and Resident
Senior Fellow at the Columbia Center on Sustainable Investment, and
author (The Myth of Capitalism: Monopolies and the Death of
Competition), Denise Hearn,
See: https://youtu.be/iJZVOsEr6aU?si=I6n-JxR5Mt04_vt-
Of
the many ProSocial interviews and discussions I have either attended
and participated in, or watched on-demand afterwards, this is one I
would certainly consider among the most important. The purpose of
the following comments is twofold: to provide some context and reason
for that assessment, and to define how a historic opportunity for the
Human Energy, ProSocial and Evolution Institute organizations
- https://www.humanenergy.io/about
- https://evolution-institute.org/
to
pursue ‘next steps’ after the recent Science
of the Noosphere
master class might be framed. And in the spirit of recognizing the
importance of this webinar, beginning with a grateful salute of
appreciation to both professor Wilson and Ms. Hearn is more than
justified.
Given
the richness and breadth of implications arising from Ms. Hearn’s
presentation and the subsequent discussion with professor Wilson, my
comments below will barely scratch the surface. But fair warning: the
intent here is to be somewhat intentionally provocative.
Because
of the definitional and intersecting thematic heterogeneities which
Ms. Hearn dissects – and quite appropriately repeatedly refers to
as “profound” - in presenting and illuminating the many facets
involved in considering the intersection of anti-trust and other
forms of regulatory commercial policy administration with
sustainability, an increasingly dour, if not grim, sense of soberness
about the severity of the challenge of seeking to realize the
objective of substantive, constructive and decisive cooperation based
on the principles of multi-level selection out of this seemingly
hopeless legal and institutional Gordian Knot seemed to palpably grow
as the discussion unfolded. This is perhaps most explicitly
acknowledged by professor Wilson himself at about the sixty-four
minute mark in the talk. Perhaps counter-intuitively, this may
actually be a very good thing. Why? A deep sense of sobriety may be
entirely appropriate given the highly non-trivial challenges –
socially, politically, scientifically, and ecologically - associated
with realizing the multi-level mandate of making the whole system the
target of selection.
Reflecting
on this presentation and discussion after a first, and then a second
viewing, revived to mind a longer-term historical perspective which
may be worth reiterating; one based on a correlated point I had
raised in a blog written in review and support of a paper professor
Wilson had co-authored with economist, Denis Snower some months ago.
In it, I offered select grounds for why certain of the current
characteristics of corporate charters should not be considered
sacrosanct nor immune from review, nor from possibly deeply
fundamental and far reaching modification of their terms and
incentive profiles, if the objective of living within planetary
boundaries – and doing so by the deep and pervasive degrees of
multi-tiered and sectoral cooperation which doing so will necessarily
require - is to ever be realized and sustained.
(See: Rethinking
The Theoretical Foundations of Economics
).
The
cited context for this suggestion was the then recent admonition by
the IPCC that, “it is clear now that minor, marginal, reactive or
incremental changes won’t be sufficient.”
As
the following very informative article lays out, efforts to address
the profound sustainability challenges we face with new
commercial/business legal-entity forms, structures and business
models have emerged, but the article itself then articulates
cautionary observations which complement the bias of the arguments to
follow in these comments that these do not obviate the need for more
deeper and more fundamental institutional innovation. Two of these
cautionary passages especially stand out. “Incorporation
laws that enable the formation of these businesses are ad hoc and
vary wildly.” This is followed, importantly, by the two closing
sentences. “We need to reform businesses so they adopt
environmental protection goals on
their own
(emphasis in the original.). This means encouraging new legal forms
of business: ones that allow the purpose, governance, and role of
profit to align with the steady-state goal.”
https://steadystate.org/redesigning-business-for-sustainability/?blm_aid=109510
In
this context it is also worth emphasizing something noteworthy: it
seems to have recently finally become acceptable to demythologize the
once virtually sacrosanct status accorded to the ‘(Milton) Friedman
Doctrine’ pronouncements and characterization of the extremely
constrained societal role and obligations of the commercial
enterprise. Recent examples include:
https://hedgehogreview.com/issues/markets-and-the-good/articles/the-myth-of-the-friedman-doctrine
https://hedgehogreview.com/issues/markets-and-the-good/articles/profit-power-and-purpose
Considering
that the first, formal corporate charter was granted by the British
Crown to the East India Company in 1600 – i.e., now well over four
hundred
years ago - and that scholars have traced other antecedent structures
sharing some similar characteristics to medieval Italy, and even as
far back as ancient Rome, there should be little surprise that these
foundational factors of the invisible legal infrastructure have come
to seem not merely sacrosanct, but have come to be mistakenly taken
by many as virtually the underlying economic equivalent of fixed
physical laws and constants of nature; perhaps especially so in the
world of finance. In reality, of course, they are nothing of the
kind; they are human constructs and, as such, potentially perfectly
malleable, pending contingencies of context, need, objectives and
priorities.
(And
a glimpse at the scholarship in economic history which has emerged in
recent years exploring why much greater appreciation for the
path-dependent nature of the institutional forms which now prevail,
and for the penumbra of interpretive nuance associated with their
original rationales and current justifications would corroborate such
a tempered perspective; e.g., see recent books by USC professor Jacob
Soll and colleagues, Glory M. Liu of Harvard, and Brad DeLong of UC
Berkeley, and their recent discussion at:
https://youtu.be/peHlMwkGnGo?si=PnuIz2xVYTYevW3X
)
The
reason for citing the deep symbiosis between the emergence of the
corporate charter and the State is that it has effectively played the
role ever since of grounding what has become a path-dependent
operational condition of virtually incontestable policy deference due
to the State priority assigned to economic conquest, expansion and
aspirations for competitive dominance. And though the process of
corporate formation evolved over time to become much more routine,
this very ease enabled their vast proliferation, while the naturally
inevitable coupling with accelerating technological advancements
morphed together until they became operationally inseparable as the
foundational ‘metabolism’ of the entire social/economic system.
But to the extent that historians concur in dating the genesis of the
modern Nation State itself to be defined by the 1648 signing of the
Treaties of Westphalia, assigning relative priority and importance
between these entities, growing ever more reinforced in their
symbiotic mutual dependence, may be considered a very interesting and
open question; as considerable contemporary scholarship indeed seems
to consider it. But given such a lengthy history of mutual
self-preservation – often rationalized in terms of ‘national
security’ - nor should it surprise that, generation after
generation, and even century after century, a self-reinforcing legion
of lawyers, lobbyists, short-sighted (even if not ethically
compromised) legislators, and apologist academic theoreticians have
become exceptionally adept at concocting rationales and mechanisms to
reinforce justifying the misplaced sense of the sacrosanct, and
assuring that any prospect of serious reevaluation, let alone actual
modification, that might jeopardize State-mediated incumbent power
and advantage would be, if not completely eliminated, minimized to
precisely change which is generally only “minor, marginal, reactive
or incremental”.
In
this sense, the Gordian Knot exposed by Ms. Hearn’s presentation,
and inclusive of arguably often spurious protestations against any
perceived challenge to their prerogatives by commercial incumbents
and their defenders, can be seen historically as the path dependent
accretion of such mechanisms of obfuscation and obstruction. And as
long as a self-serving culture of Social Darwinist rationalizations
could be invoked in justification, and as long as social and
political manipulations were available to contain any backlash
challenges – prospective or actual - arising from ‘mere’ human
suffering resulting from the specific formulation of this paradigm,
maintaining this conditionally baked-in status quo inertia could be
and has been reliable and incredibly durable over time; even if at
the expense of such an ever expanding legal definitional Gordian Knot
fur ball as illuminated here. Until now.
As
increasingly evidenced by climate-reality acknowledgment from the
insurance, re-insurance and a growing number of other industries -
with the backlash against narrow incumbent privilege effectively
coming not (yet) from a revolutionary human rabble brandishing
pitchforks and guillotines, but from the planet itself - the
historical perspective invoked above suggests that what we are seeing
emerge is a classic collision between an ostensibly immovable object
with an irresistible force playing out as a kind of existential game
of chicken.
But
the historically tried-and-true immovability posturing of incumbent
legal gamesmanship is now up against this stark reality for the first
time: the actually
irresistible force of the planet, and its’ very real biophysical
and geophysical limits, could not be more indifferent to legal
gamesmanship because the laws of physics and chemistry by which it
operates simply aren’t playing; the dynamics of those entropic and
other physical laws are perfectly willing to steamroll right over the
legal, financial, legislative, academic or other ‘masters of the
universe’ who continue to presume, in spite of all evidence to the
contrary, that their narrow parochial exercise of legal, legislative
and institutional tactics designed to eliminate or constrain change
to the “minor, marginal, reactive or incremental’ can again
prevail as they largely always have; a very bad bet indeed since
‘prevailing’, in this case, courts the equally very real
entailment of civilizational consequences of potential suicidal
moment, notwithstanding derisive accusatory invocations of ‘climate
catasrophizing’ by the dwindling cadre of those determined to
remain devotees of climate-change denialism, in disregard of all
mounting experiential evidence and increasing rigor in scientific
modeling and inference to the contrary.
One
intention here is to suggest that considering the severity of the
Gordian Knot noted above as a kind of symptomatic metric of the
historic significance of the impending transition would be a more
than merely justified framing, and that the virtually reflexive
incumbent attempts to limit change to the “minor, marginal,
reactive or incremental’ now so broadly evident are simultaneously
misguided, tinged with a scent of the desperate, illustrative of a
severe underestimation of this historic significance, and reflective
of an almost dizzyingly disorienting deficit of institutional and
administrative imagination. In one sense, this final deficit is
understandable since the default political and legal tendency is to
address problems by not looking beyond the many implicated ‘silos’
but to merely tweak at this familiar proximate level as timidly as it
is possible to get away with. Recognizing this, a further intended
suggestion of these comments is that it may be equally misguided and
futile to envision resolving this Gordian Knot by such piecemeal
means. But suggesting this naturally begs the questions, ‘why’,
and ‘what is the alternative’?
To
approach an answer for the first question, it may be useful to
mentally rewind the clock to the year 1600 and ask the following:
what was the imperative at that time which made necessary the
structuring of that initial corporate charter by the British Crown?
Answer: the need to distribute the risk of the otherwise overwhelming
cost and other expeditionary demands of realizing the Crown’s
exploration and expansionist economic objectives. With that in mind,
but returning to the present, the problem now is precisely that the
political/governmental, institutional, legal and financial
antecedents then instantiated to satisfy those objectives have
ravenously expanded and taken on a life of their own to the point
where their reflexive tendencies of self-perpetuation now obstruct
broader systemic resilience; obstruct allowing appropriate systemic
adaptations even though the current
driving imperative is dramatically altered from what it was judged to
be in 1600; largely precisely because of the amplifying feedback
dynamics and associated exponential successes of what was unleashed
in 1600. And lest anyone imagine that State/econo-financial
symbiosis as the key driver of nearly unconditional policy deference
can be left as a relic of history associated exclusively with the
colonial era, a recent book may help to disabuse any such notion: The
Underground Empire,
by Henry Farrell and Abraham Newman
(see: https://us.macmillan.com/books/9781250840554/undergroundempire
).
And
in a very important sense, even though it may seem obvious that
interrogating the nature of our current driving imperative would lead
to an answer focused on addressing the highly multi-dimensional
‘wicked problem’ of the climate challenge, a strong case could be
made that this, though clearly necessary, may itself be regarded as
relatively proximate and symptomatic; that what is more deeply
primary is actually a governance meta-challenge: i.e., how to make
endogenous to the very process of governance the imperative to enable
resilient adaptation of its’ own processes so that necessary and
constructive modifications to its’ own modes of operation, policies
and objectives are facilitated rather than being allowed to become
ossified sources of self-perpetuating obstruction to such
adaptations; significantly via various forms of ‘capture’ by both
commercial and political incumbents seeking to diffuse disadvantage
anticipated from the needed modifications.
One
prominent, and often even reflexive, response to this is easy to
anticipate. Many would vociferously argue that these are precisely
the adaptive capabilities already available to us through democracy.
But the reality is far more problematic and nuanced. Not unlike the
fact that there are many forms or realizations of ‘capitalism’,
to realize (or not) such an adaptive ideal via democracy, the form
of the democratic system matters, and it matters a
lot.
For ‘exhibit A’, we need look no further than the shocking level
of virtually adolescent dysfunction currently on display in the
legislative branch of the U.S. Federal government. But more
generally, current forms of democracy (U.S. included) are not even
close to satisfying the ideal with respect one of the most important
organizing and driving forces in social life: economics.
Amazingly,
with the exception of taxation and trade issues, and in spite of how
categorically fundamental to life this factor is, it is almost
completely absent from the founding documents defining the U.S.
republic; many, if not most, of whose founders were, as is generally
well recognized, (white) men of either relative affluence or of
actual economically independent means. From the perspective of today
- especially after the revelations provided by the scholarship of
Thomas Piketty regarding how inextricable ownership of capital
assets, and the income streams they can provide, are to securing
wealth - one can only stand somewhat agog that, after stipulating as
universal and inalienable the rights to life, liberty and the pursuit
of happiness, the founding documents remain so conspicuously mute
about making explicit, universal participatory economic rights for
citizens so as to assure enabling the living realization of
those higher, more normative and abstract rights for which the
American Declaration of Independence is so rightly renowned.
(For
a deeply researched narrative of how contentious the process of U.S.
Constitutional passage was, how very narrowly it passed, which class
and economic interests were subordinated, how and why, and which
managed to ascend and prevail as superordinate because of whose
voices were granted most prominence, a very strong recommendation is
given to: The
Framer’s Coup: The Making of the United States Constitution,
by Michael J. Klarman. See: https://hls.harvard.edu/bibliography/the-framers-coup-the-making-of-the-united-states-constitution/
.)
In
spite of the growing prevalence of politically-correct, socially
placating lip service given at now untold numbers of World Economic
Forum or other think tank or academic presentations, and/or panel
discussions in recent years – often enunciated in a ‘green
washing’ or other political PR context - to how dire the need is to
address economic inequality, why are the economic and financial
‘rules of the game’ still written not merely to enable, but to
insure that ownership of productive capital assets – as Piketty
illuminated, the real wellspring of wealth - remain concentrated in
the hands of a vanishingly small subset of the population instead of
writing them to insure the opposite; i.e., that such ownership be
made universal as a natural right of every (global) citizen,
necessary to attain life, liberty and the pursuit of happiness? Why
are we still clinging to the social and economic opportunity-cost
tragedy, yet almost comically anachronistic idea, that the only
viable mechanism for the mass distribution of income is through the
sale of labor? The institutional forms and associated legally
defined constraints which have locked us into this misguided path
generation after generation are one perfect example of precisely the
suggested de facto State grant of, and sustaining deference to what
has become a severely anachronistic economic/financial/legal/academic
status quo, and one contrary to the kind of systemically integrated
change the IPCC is calling for. (And more than merely incidentally,
a deference which was on full display during the aftermath of the
2007/8 economic crisis when recommendations for defining the terms in
which post-crisis evaluation should be conducted and, then, what
actual policy decisions should be taken in the wake of the crisis,
came almost exclusively from this ‘priesthood’ of the status quo;
having everything to do with propping up extant institutions and
highly selective individual privilege rather than re-envisioning or
seriously considering deeply fundamental theoretical and structural
change; an enormous missed opportunity.)
The
Founders at least had as tacit excuse for their sins-of-omission the
fact that, in their pre-Industrial-Revolution era, still dominated by
a nearly exclusively labor-based, agrarian economy, they could not be
expected to anticipate how absolutely indispensable to the generation
and maintenance of personal wealth and individual economic viability,
competence and political autonomy the advances of technology would
become. Anyone pleading ignorance of this dependence today would be
suspect of either acute deficiencies of observation and inferential
capacity, and/or a surfeit of guile so disingenuous that only among
an audience populated by the similarly afflicted would there be any
hope of not being laughed out of the room; or perhaps pelted out with
rotten eggs and moldy tomatoes. Indeed, one measure of just how
pervasive the brain washing is, might be crystallized with a
corollary question: why in the world has the labor-union movement not
long ago abandoned maintaining highly counter-productive
labor/capital antagonism in favor of recognition that the far more
potent – to say nothing of mutually beneficial - objective would be
to collectively bargain for expanding, and ultimately universalizing,
participation in ownership of the capital itself? Yet this
extraordinary and unconscionable regime of exclusionary and highly
concentrated ownership rights remains unscathed not merely decade
after decade, but century after century; notwithstanding the current
displays of crocodile tears of concern and hand wringing over the
need for more equitable distributions of wealth. And this reality
bears on a significant instance of, and exercise in the abuse of
language intimately related to these considerations, and one which is
frequently invoked, not infrequently, in paeans of nationalistic
self-congratulation.
The
American economic system is often said to be the embodiment of
‘democratic capitalism’. Oh really? While, yes, a republic
having electoral political representation is certainly consistent
with democratic principles, the absence of any formal Constitutional
or other fundamental and universal, rights-based legislated linkages
between political suffrage, and provisions explicitly stipulating and
ensuring a citizen’s universal right for what might be called
‘economic suffrage’, the nearly exclusive reliance for earning a
livelihood of the vast majority of citizens on the fickle
vicissitudes often associated with the sale of their labor (i.e.,
‘wage slavery’), and their nearly total exclusion from meaningful
participation in the markets for ownership of productive capital
assets and their associated income streams, embodies nothing remotely
close to a system of decisional citizen agency inclusive of such
rights, and thus deserving to be characterized as ‘democratic
capitalism’. (Of considerable historic note, and to their great
credit, both Thomas Jefferson and Abraham Lincoln intuitively grasped
an important related truth: the independence-of-mind and relative
immunity from economic or other influences of coercion with which
political suffrage can be exercised will also be a diminished, if not
nominal, thing in the absence of such broader and more inclusive
‘economic suffrage’ and independence.) The more cynical or
conspiratorially minded might be forgiven for inferring that perhaps
this is precisely the point, and that this conceptually utterly
unnecessary political/economic schism is both how and why such a
socially perversely exclusionary regime could be sustained and
allowed to persist for so long. (As a brief aside, in another of
professor Wilson’s recent ProSocial webinars - with Jerome Warren
on the subject of Cooperatives - Mr. Warren makes reference to the
fact that the Italian Constitution explicitly does
make provision for what has apparently become an extremely diverse,
creatively vibrant, highly productive, growing and substantive
ecosystem of cooperatives within Italy; a not insignificant fact
which might hold interesting promise as a possible model to
internationally encourage dissolution of this political/economic
schism, in spite of the case to be made that the cooperative, as an
institutional form, might be reasonably characterized, for all its’
benefits, as a kind of desperate social ‘backdoor’ compromise
effectively compelled by exactly the absence of the broader, and more
institutionally formal ‘economic suffrage’ only intimated above,
but fully possible.)
Returning
now to address the second part of the question posed above – i.e.,
what is the alternative to piecemeal efforts to disentangle the
Gordian Knot illuminated by Ms. Hearn’s presentation – may be
best approached by momentarily stepping back for a bit of
reorientation.
The
Systems Change Lab is an organization doing very important work. A
passage from comments opening a training webinar recently conducted
to guide users on how to navigate and leverage the many resources
which their powerful website offers, provides exactly the
reorientation needed here. (See: https://youtu.be/y0vBfOtMCJQ?si=Bexq9CUb-wb4Vn28
). And the attentive reader will also notice that this passage is
also highly complementary with the IPCC excerpt cited above.
“Nearly
every major system will need to transform. This includes things like
how we power our economies, how we grow food, build cities, conserve
nature and beyond. And
additionally, cross cutting transitions also need to occur in our
political, social and economic systems. By using system syncing we
know that these changes are complex and interconnected, and we can’t
change one system without changing others.”
(Bold/italic emphasis added.)
The
relevance of this passage for purposes of imagining alternatives to
disentangling by piecemeal means the Gordian Knot noted above is
insidiously easy to overlook. Such means tacitly assume that the
identity of the ‘pieces’ would remain essentially unaltered by
any successful disentangling. As such, the effort effectively
devolves to an exercise of tweaking within the parameters of that
assumption. But under conditions of highly multi-dimensional
integration suggested in both the passage just quoted, as with the
previous IPCC excerpt, it is often the very identity of the ‘pieces’,
how they are organized, and literally the semantics of the very
criteria in terms of which any needed disentangling would take place
which cannot be assumed to have remained stable and fixed. In fact,
in this sense, a more appropriate characterization of the scenario
may actually be far less a case of disentangling at all, and far more
a case of creative and systemically re-conceptualizing according to a
new systemic gestalt whose defining causal and semantic profile might
be quite distinct from that which led to the original ‘knotting’.
In
this case, just one example of what would likely be a quite severe
incongruity with the historically path-dependent existing gestalt out
of which that dread Gordian Knot emerged, would be any new system
design which ceases to continue
granting the virtually incontestable operational and policy deference
to the State/economy alignment which prevails in the current
paradigm; a deference which, both historically and to this very day,
effectively entails that every other aspect of the system must
effectively play ‘second fiddle’ because they remain bound and
inhibited within the legal/financial prerogatives and associated
institutional constraints of that alignment; health and viability of
the planet, or any
other
priority be damned. Hence, consider the famous quip by political
advisor to former President Clinton, James Carville: "I
used to think that if there was reincarnation, I wanted to come back
as the president or the pope or as a .400 baseball hitter. But now I
would like to come back as the bond market. You can intimidate
everybody."
Hence, consider the growing ranks of global corporations reneging on
prior net-zero or other climate ‘commitments’, even while their
‘green washing’ PR campaigns may continue unabated in striving to
associate themselves with, and portray themselves as responsible
participants in the very transition they are betraying; something
which further betrays a kind of theoretical, institutional and,
indeed, even systemic schizophrenia which dare not be acknowledged
even though failure to acknowledge it simply compounds both the
betrayal and the schizophrenia, assuring that the civilizational
existential game of chicken persists.
Understood
in this light, the protestations proclaiming ‘democratic
capitalism’ suddenly deflate almost to the point of farce, being
more worthy of ridicule rather than justification with
quasi-theological allegiance; and though misguided, an allegiance so
potent, that its’ grant of deference and license has been many
times invoked – not infrequently by rousing nationalistic tribalism
- to rationalize and justify policies and exercises of power that it
is unlikely any authentically democratic process would ever sanction.
And
if the revelations of Ms. Hearn were not enough, further basis for
the increasing sense of soberness observed over the course of
discussion during this webinar is provided by the following excerpt
from professor Katharina Pistor’s very important 2019 book, The
Code of Capital: How the Law Creates Wealth and Inequality:
“Like
most empires of the past, the empire of law is a patchwork; it
consists not of a single global law, but of select domestic laws that
are knit together by rules, including conflict-of-law rules that
ensure the recognition and enforcement of these domestic laws
elsewhere, as well as select international treaty law. The
decentered nature of the law that is used to code global capital has
many advantages. It means that global commerce and finance can
thrive without a global state or a global law; and it allows those in
the know to pick and choose the rules that best suit their or their
clients’ interests. In this way, the empire of law severs the
umbilical cord between the individual’s self-interest and social
concerns. The legal decoding of capital reveals Smith’s invisible
hand as a substitute for a reliable legal code – visible even if
often hidden from sight, and with a legal infrastructure firmly in
place that is global in scope – that is no longer serving its
purpose. Effective legal protection almost anywhere allows private
self-interest to flourish without the need to return home to benefit
from local institutions. Capital coded in portable law is footloose;
gains can be made and pocketed anywhere and the losses can be left
wherever they fall.”
How
non-trivial this passage is in the context of this webinar, the
context of professor Wilson and Snower’s recognition and
explanation of the evolutionary reasons that the validity of Smith’s
‘Invisible Hand’ metaphor must be seen as contextually
conditional rather than the categorical universal it is traditionally
asserted to be, or of Ms. Hearn’s important acknowledgment that the
now anachronistic nature of key tenets of neoclassical economics
renders it hopelessly insufficient as a basis for providing guidance
to anti-trust administrators who might recognize the imperative of
applying multi-level selection criteria in executing their
professional oversight duties relating to mergers, and/or allowable
levels of cooperation among firms in service of attaining ecological
sustainability, and its’ importance in the context of the
suggestion raised in these comments that the exact nature of these
very duties might be markedly different from how they are manifest at
present if the terms defining rights and obligations in corporate
charters were altered to be consistent with those criteria rather
than antagonistic to them, all would be difficult to overstate. And
how non-trivial it is for the prospect of authentic democratic
governance is compounded by the following somewhat more extended
passage appearing a bit further in professor Pistor’s book under
the sub-heading, An
Exorbitant Privilege:
“The
story about capital and its legal code is complicated as the legal
modules that are used are complex and hidden in arcane statutory or
case law and the plot frequently develops behind the closed doors of
large law firms, with only a rare airing in a court of law or
parliament. The legal code confers attributes that greatly enhance
the prospects of some assets and their respective owners to amass
wealth relative to others – an exorbitant privilege. Choosing the
assets and grafting onto them the legal attributes of priority,
durability, universality, and convertibility is tantamount to
controlling the levers for the distribution of wealth in society.
“This
account contradicts the standard argument that capitalist economies
are defined by free markets that allocate scarce resources
efficiently and that prices reflect the fundamental value of assets.
Many legal scholars have already drawn attention to the fact that the
operation of the market hinges on legal institutions that facilitate
price discovery. I go a step further and argue that the legal coding
accounts for the value of assets, and thus for the creation of wealth
and its distribution. This should be only too apparent with respect
to financial assets and intellectual property rights that do not
exist outside the law. However, it is also true for simpler assets
that were used as the prototypes for legal coding, such as land or
pools of assets held together in firms.
“States
and state law are central to the coding of capital. States have not
only dismantled existing rights and privilege to make room for the
power of market forces, as Polanyi has pointed out. Capital and
capitalism would not exist without the coercive power of states.
States often do not, in fact they need not, control the legal coding
process itself. Indeed, at the frontiers where new capital rights
are minted day by day in the offices of law firms, states take a back
seat. But states provide the legal tools that lawyers use; and they
offer their law enforcement apparatus to enforce the capital that
lawyers have crafted. Not all coding strategies will go
unchallenged, and some of them
will
be struck down at a future date. Many, however, will never be
scrutinized, and others will survive the challenge; and the few that
are eventually struck down often have already produced fortunes for
their holders.
“The
ability to graft the code’s modules onto an ever changing roster of
assets makes lawyers the true masters of the code of capital. In
principle, anyone has access to lawyers and their coding skills, but
the market for legal services ensures that only the best-paying
clients can hire the most skillful among them. The specifics about
how assets are selected for legal coding are rarely scrutinized. The
common depictions of law as stable, almost sacrosanct, immunize from
the public eye the work that is done more and more in private law
firms, and less and less in parliaments or even court rooms.
“The
state’s willingness to recognize and enforce privately coded
capital, indeed to foster it by recognizing innovative coding
strategies and the expansion of asset classes that can be legally
coded as capital, may seem puzzling. Many a state has fallen for the
promise that expanding the legal options for some, including offering
them exemptions from general laws and other legal privileges, will
enlarge the pie and offer greater prosperity for all. They
frequently realize only later, that the trickle is often rather
small. More important, most of the benefits from capital do not
trickle down; they trickle up to capital holders who repatriate their
gains or place them behind the legal shields other jurisdictions
afford them to protect their wealth from tax and other creditors.
“Another
explanation is that states themselves have more to gain than to lose
from privileging capital by backing the private coding efforts that
create it. States benefit from economic growth, because it boosts
their tax revenue and allows them to raise debt finance. The fate of
governments in democracies in particular has been tied ever more
closely to their governments’ ability to produce growth. Growth
rates, and the rise of stock markets, not the distribution of wealth
or indices of human development, have become the standard measures
for adjudicating success or failure of elected governments – in
itself an indicator of the enormous cognitive sway capital has over
politics. Yet, as many states have realized, the power of the tax
sword has been blunted by sophisticated legal coding strategies that
can hide assets from their reach. Even more generally, promoting the
interests of capital first and foremost boosts private, not
necessarily national, wealth and thereby fosters inequality. To see
why this is so, we need to decode the legal structures of capital.”
There
are at least two reasons for providing such an extended excerpt.
First, the expert perspectives offered in it strongly reinforce
recognition of several important factors: the depth and scope of
State/economy symbiosis, the insidious nature of some of its
implications in the global context, how these interface with the
Gordian Knot illuminated in this webinar, and what this entails for
the challenge of system change. But a second reason is to suggest
that the very plasticity of the legal coding process presents a
potentially positive flip side. In fact, professor Pistor herself
intimates such possibilities when she references a very interesting
and suggestive case brought before the Supreme Court in Belize by the
Mayan tribe. In summary, she notes:
“But
the story of the Maya and their quest to legally code their claims to
the land also
holds the promise that legal coding might be used for purposes other
than private wealth maximization;
as the reasoning of the highest court in Belize suggests, property
rights can take many shapes, and forms and they might just as well be
used to protect collective use rights and sustainable practices
(emphasis
added).”
Part
of the reason for highlighting this passage is the obvious salience
it holds in the context of professor Wilson and Snower’s concerns
to inform economic theory, practice and institutional design with
insights from multi-level selection theory, including “collective
use” scenarios. And if the plasticity of legal coding can serve in
support of the “many shapes, and forms” in which property rights
might be embodied for something as basic and fundamental as land, it
is not a wild stretch to suggest that the possibilities for the other
more intangible or sometimes even rarefied legal modules which
professor Pistor addresses might hold even more creative potential.
And this very possibility interfaces with another related context and
perspective having great salience and enormous importance to the
subject of this webinar. It comes from the very important recent
book by professors David G. Victor and Charles F. Sabel, Fixing
the Climate: Strategies for an Uncertain World.
While this excerpt from the subsection, Governance,
appearing in chapter 3, Theory
of Experimentalist Governance,
will also be of some extent, the reason for the indulgence should be
almost immediately apparent.
“ .
. . It is governance that determines whether regulation is
adversarial or cooperative, and what those terms actually mean.
“Because
governance links formal law to informal practice and public to
private decision-making, it is sensitive to changes in economic and
political conditions often well before such changes prompt
reconsideration of legislation or regulatory rules – if they ever
do. In short, law tends to lag where governance leads. For this
reason, governance is frequently the language in which think tankers,
academics, and business leaders broach proposals for reform too
urgent to be postponed, yet too speculative to be codified into law.
From this point of view, governance is a kind of test bed for urgent
and often highly consequential adjustments to new circumstances.
“The
rise of uncertainty is recasting the nature of the governance
problem. For most of the last century, governance debates have been
concerned with determining the identities and aligning the interests
of principals and their agents. On this model, principals –
whether the sovereign people, a legislative body, government
administrator, controlling owner of a corporation, or corporate
manager – have plans and projects. But to realize these plans,
principals must rely on agents with interests of their own. If the
background conditions are fixed, the principal’s problem is to
devise an incentive system that induces agents to spend their efforts
in achieving their goal rather than using the discretion their
position affords to disguise self-interested behavior as dedication
to the project. For instance, tying manager compensation to stock
price increases links the interests of principals and agents when the
principals are shareholders.
“When
the background conditions are changing, however – as is typical of
the episodes that provoke a concern with governance – the problem
of aligning interests becomes entwined with the larger problem of
determining which actors should be principals in the first place. . .
.
“Even
as these debates continue, the principal-agent relationship has been
breaking down under uncertainty – first in pockets of the economy
(like automobiles and semi-conductors) and areas of regulation (like
pharmaceuticals or air pollution) especially exposed to rapid change,
and then in fits and starts more generally. In a risky world, actors
can assign probabilities to outcomes and incentivize behavior that
leads to the desired ones. Under uncertainty, it’s impossible to
anticipate what outcomes will be and hence impossible to assign them
probabilities. In these circumstances, the challenge for governance
changes radically. Under uncertainty, no actor alone can formulate
plans with the precision and confidence necessary to engage agents
for precise tasks, let alone devise methods to incentivize and hold
them accountable. Conception cannot usefully be separated from
execution. Actors instead have to collaborate, defining projects in
the very process of trying to carry them forward, and using such
progress as they make to reassess the feasibility of the undertaking
along with the capabilities and reliability of their partners. In a
stable world, in other words, agents execute steps in the plans of
their principals, and the fact of their interdependence is covered
over by the serviceable fiction that the principal is in control.
Under uncertainty, however, planning and execution are inextricably
connected; pooling their knowledge and experience, actors use the
execution of provisional plans to revise their joint goals. Their
mutual dependence is as open as the fallibility of their projects.
“Over
the last few decades, in advanced sectors of the economy and public
administration, this kind of collaboration has been institutionalized
and given legal form, keeping cooperating actors accountable to each
other despite the fluidity of their relations and transience of their
plans, and thus protecting them against the vulnerabilities that
their interdependence creates. Organizations are designed so that
anomalies and surprises touch off an investigation of possible
improvements rather than efforts to enforce the existing structure
against newly identified risks. Regulations and contracts, long
intended to be proof against every imaginable contingency, are
likewise being reconceived as open to learning through use. The form
of administrative decision-making is shifting as well, from the
promulgation of rules to the issuance of guidance, in recognition of
the impossibility of certitude and therefore the acceptance that
directives will routinely need to be revised.”
The
attentive reader will notice several sections in these passages of
obviously high relevance either to the specific subject of this
webinar and/or these comments more broadly.
Further,
an important, though generally unacknowledged, part of exploring what
alternative there might be to the otherwise excruciating prospect of
attempting a piecemeal disentangling of the current regulatory, legal
and econo-financial Gordian Knot is first to recognize this: that the
knot is, to begin with, a reflection of, emerged because, and is one
glaring embodiment of the fundamental inconsistency and conflict
between human economic/financial, legal, institutional and social
constructs which treat as ‘externalities’ natural processes and
limits which are, in reality, foundational and endogenous and the
factual, geophysical and biophysical scientific realities of the
biosphere; a reality not yet recognized when the path-dependent
historical process of institutional design and theoretical framing we
have inherited, and are now constrained by, began four hundred years
ago.
But now, appropriate recognition of the
endogeneity just noted
demands
the further recognition that the two stand not statically in an
equilibrium relation to each other, merely as predefined subset to
super-set, but in relational modes which are of a highly interactive,
dynamic, interpenetrating, mutually generative nature and, therefore,
complex, as opposed to merely ‘complicated’. By comparison, the
merely complicated is easy; it can be algorithmically simulated while
real complexity cannot. And it is real complexity, and the
unanticipated and not
predefined emergence of often surprising and disruptive novelty
associated with it, that is at the root of the ‘wicked problem’
scenarios with which our social, economic, legal and governance
institutions are continually confronted, and which provides another
way to frame why the vision for their design on the basis of
“experimental governance” principles enhances the chance to
contend with them effectively; with climate change, per se, being
almost certainly the most encompassing, though not exclusive, of such
scenarios. Failure of such design leads to the Gordian Knot problem
on display in this webinar by frequently, but perhaps often
unnecessarily, imposing an impossible square peg-round hole problem
associated with the exogeneity/endogeneity conflict just noted.
With
this in mind, with the reality of planetary limits in mind, and
recognizing how complementary principles of experimental governance
are with the principles of multi-level selection, with the core
design principles elaborated by Nobel laureate, Elinor Ostrom, and
professor Wilson’s call for ‘the supremacy of the global’,
coupled with ‘the subsidiarity of the local’ begs this very
interesting question: how might the laws for corporate charters be
reformulated to complement this, and how far might this go to not so
much cut or disentangle the existing Gordian Knot illuminated in this
webinar but, in effect, to dissolve it?
And
given such a reformulation, another deeply important, interesting and
challenging question follows.
A
concept central to free-market, capitalist economics, as both an
ideology and a putative science, is that of self-equilibration;
generally construed in a price-auction, supply/demand framing;
effectively, the tacit embodiment of the misguided equilibrium
presumption foundational to neoclassical economics. But if a
reformulation of corporate and economic law is to be a key part of
modifying capitalist market economies so as to remove the numero uno
deference they have effectively been accorded for over four hundred
years to operate as if biophysical constraints and limits do not
exist on the resource extraction, product production, waste, and the
perpetual growth taken for granted by this presumption, when it
becomes necessary to systemically include into a new global economic
and financial metabolism operational recognition that they, in
reality, do
exist – as is beginning to occur now - what would the institutional
and market redesigns need to look like to instantiate a legitimate
concept of endogenous economic self-equilibration when that
endogeneity must comprehend being truly systemic of global ecology,
writ large, rather than merely the human production/consumption
economics where the prevailing, much more narrow, incomplete and
flawed equilibrium framing and institutional infrastructure
associated with these, obtains? Merely posing this question
explicitly unleashes a cascade of others; in addition to those
pertaining to the administration of corporate law directly addressed
in this webinar, others might include, whether prevailing
private-banking, debt-based monetary theory and operations are
complementary or antagonistic of this more expansive scenario; of the
existing universe of financial instruments, which might remain
complementary and which would need to be judged antagonistic; related
to both of these, are extant configurations and ‘metabolic’
implications of both primary and secondary market structures and
operations complementary or antagonistic? The preceding unleash yet
another question which is especially important to consider.
By
implication, these questions are intimately related to a cluster of
important concepts at the intersection of conservation and ecological
economics: e.g., the valuation of ecosystem services, when ‘markets’
for natural resources/capital are either highly inefficient or
actually non-existent, and others. But systemically speaking, there
is a potentially highly non-trivial ‘rub’ involved in the first
of these. When we identify and mentally segregate for valuation
purposes a given property of an ecosystem – e.g., watershed
dynamics, or the relative vitality of the soil microbiome - and
assign to it the designation of ‘service’, we impose, knowingly
or not, a potential functional/causal and relational duality: the
‘service’ that it seems to provide us,
and the natural functions (note the plural) that it may fulfill in
the ecosystem, per se, when not subject to human intrusion. In other
words, by our choosing to prioritize for valuation purposes such a
mentally segregated ‘service’, how the dynamics and coupling of
that ‘service’ is effected by market operations as a consequence
of the particular ‘value’ we assign to that selection for
whatever specific utility it is observed to provide to us,
will not necessarily comport with how the ecosystem itself
relationally embeds or ‘values’ the functional and causal
tentacles of that property in time, space or feedback dynamics within
the total embedding ecosystem. And if maintaining the latter, based
on principles of multi-level selection, is taken to be the ideal
target of selection, the divergence between the two, and its’
relative stability given selection, becomes an important governance
and data/tracking consideration. One reason for this importance
relates to potential sources of divergence over time; examples
include possible systemic ‘service’ co-benefits having
potentially non-trivial feedback/rebound effects, difficulty or even
impossibility of formally assigning monetary value to intangible, and
often highly value-laden normative properties which the ‘service’
or the larger ecology within which it is embedded may hold for
various constituencies, and last-but-not-least, trade-offs. A recent
IIASA webinar is of considerable merit on these points.
See: https://www.youtube.com/live/xCgtvRCKKYw?si=JTL6ibicgPUDCAdS
These
understated observations also bring to mind a couple of cautionary
passages by editors, Charles G. Curtain and Timothy F.H. Allen, from
their book offering a collection of scholarly papers, Complex
Ecology: Foundational Perspectives on Dynamic Approaches to Ecology
and Conservation:
“This
means designing systems that can learn and adapt, so the process
itself is essentially an experiment in which those involved learn
from the experience. However, over 40 years of adaptive management
have shown the concept is relatively easy in theory, and extremely
hard in practice.”
And
then, near the end of the book, the following excerpt expanding on
why it is so “hard in practice” is telling in several respects.
“While
a command-control strategy is efficient and necessary in situations
where rapid and directed action is needed (as in war), with long term
and large scale challenges it is frequently counter productive for it
assumes a level of continuity and predictability that was probably
never realistic, but is especially unrealistic in an era of
increasing rates of social and environmental change. This rigidity
of design means that in the face of adversity they are intrinsically
maladapted for they are always a step behind the latest perturbation
(Holling 1986, Holling and Meffe 1996).
“Essentially
the intent of governments is to maintain existing power structures,
not to sustain social and ecological integrity (Schumpter 1942,
Homer-Dixon 2006). For power relationships are frequently at odds
with long term sustainability (e.g. Tainter 1990). In essence,
governance arrangements too often work to sustain existing
institutions,
rather
than promote the institutional flexibility necessary to maintain the
overall continuity of socio-ecological systems over the long haul. . . . Short-term competitiveness and long-term resilience are too
often at odds for the very processes that make systems competitive in
the short term, predispose them to failure over time (e.g. Tainter
1990).”
(Bold emphasis added.)
“Ostrom’s
approach is predicated not on maximizing short term productivity, but
on sustaining both social and ecological systems. This is
accomplished through positive feedback loops that are not about
control and resource concentration. Rather they are about promoting
innovation to facilitate the processes whereby systems are sustained
through learning, adaptation, and response to change (e.g. Meadows
1999, Article 30).”
Given
the extent to which this invaluable collection of papers illuminates
that, after many decades of quiet development, conservation science
and scholarship itself has become broad, deep, and conceptually and
analytically sophisticated, the fact that its’ insights and lessons
have continued to formally remain largely excluded from institutions
of governance at most, if not all, scales, and certainly have not
theoretically informed or been integrated into operational economic
and financial practice or institutional structures, should make the
second of those excerpt passages every bit as sobering as this
webinar ultimately became. Further, it should amplify awareness that
the Gordian Knot the webinar unpacks effectively embodies the depth
of the mutually reinforcing symbiosis between the State, and how the
economy is currently theoretically framed and institutionally
structured. And with that amplification constituting a reasonable
measure of how historically significant the transition before us is,
it should
also instill a sense for how much an impediment
the reflexive tendencies of status quo self-preservation this
symbiote will present to making that transition. It should also
provide at least an inkling of how deeply complementary this body of
work is with the implications of professor Wilson’s theory of
multi-level selection; something which should probably not come as a
surprise since the natural systems with which conservation science
largely deals are the living embodiment of such multi-level
processes. But this is a decidedly mixed blessing; on the one hand,
that very embodiment provides a kind of de facto conceptual
corroboration from a scientific close cousin while, on the other
hand, offering little hope that mere conceptual and scientific
substance and significance will suffice to assure that the scales
will fall from the eyes of recalcitrant entrenched academic,
commercial or policy sources of denial and resistance.
While
it is increasingly widely recognized by the growing cadre of
important scholars involved in reevaluating economics – examples of
such ‘renegade’ voices might include Jeremy Rifkin, Mariana
Mazzucato, Steve Keen, Kate Raworth, Doyne Farmer and others – that
the conceptual and mathematical armory applied to the study of
biological systems constitutes a far more appropriate means of
modeling and understanding economic processes, recognition of this
may have stimulated far less consideration than is warranted of what
this may entail in terms of how the institutional infrastructure of
the economy may need to be modified to satisfy the kind of globally
systemic objective suggested.
Convention
insists that truly
fundamental economic and financial conceptual, legal and
institutional modification is not required; that merely tweaking
factors-of-adjustment such as imposition of carbon pricing,
bolstering the regulatory regime and, of course, buying in to the
techno-optimist assumption that technological fixes are sufficient to
realize the objective of a condition of socio-economic and ecological
self-equilibration. But, in the first instance, from the perspective
of ecological or regenerative economics, the very need to graft onto
the system such a post-hoc, often far from perfectly objective
cost/valuation assignments – even if only on an accounting, as
opposed to a market basis - already represents a glaring theoretical
and conceptual void representative of failing to see and design
institutional structures in systemic terms; in the second instance,
trying to accommodate the stated systemic-equilibration objective
within the complex and highly non-linear dynamics of the living
biosphere, while otherwise maintaining unscathed the extractive,
perpetual-growth dynamic baked in to the unquestioned structural
deference and priority accorded to the extant economic
price-auction-efficiency, and private-banking, debt-based monetary
regime in the face of the causally and functionally teaming and
interpenetrating heterogeneity of the biosphere would impose perhaps
impossible regulatory and administrative burdens. For the third
instance (i.e., technological fixes), a level of nuance is required
that it is generally not accorded. But, due to its’ importance,
there may be no more appropriate basis for beginning to steer these
comments toward closure in service of the objective stated at the
outset, viz. a science of the Noosphere, than striving to provide at
least a measure of this nuance.
Tempting
as it is to pursue this by directly providing examples of, and
exploring how far various emerging, and truly revolutionary
technological innovations may be for pushing the
production/consumption frontier toward viability with planetary
boundaries, the purpose may be better served by stepping back to
instead frame these considerations in terms of principles. Doing
this is very well served by invoking several passages from the truly
excellent book, An
Introduction to Ecological Economics,
(Robert Costanza, John H. Cumberland, Herman Daly, Robert Goodland,
Richard B. Norgaard, Ida Kubiszewski, and Carol Franco). To start,
the Chapter 3 sub-heading entitled, “Complementarity,
Substitutability, and Fundamental Limits”
is almost perfectly on point with the key principle:
Pg.
95
“A
standard assumption of Neoclassical economics has been that factors
of production are highly substitutable. Although other models of
production have considered factors as not at all substitutable (e.g.,
the total complementarity of the Leontief model), the
substitutability assumption has dominated. Consequently, the very
idea of a limiting factor was pushed into the background. If factors
are substitutes rather than complements, then there can be no
limiting factor and hence no new era based on a change of the
limiting role from one factor to another. It is therefore important
to be very clear on the issue of complementarity versus
substitutability.
“The
productivity of human-made capital is more and more limited by the
decreasing supply of complementary natural capital. Of course, in
the past, when the scale of the human presence in the biosphere was
low, human-made capital played the limiting role. The switch from
human-made to natural capital as the limiting factor is thus a
function of the increasing scale and impact of the human presence.
Natural capital is the stock that yields the flow of natural
resources – the forest that yields the flow of cut timber; the
petroleum deposits that yield the flow of pumped crude oil; the fish
populations in the sea that yield the flow of caught fish. The
complementary nature of natural and human-made capital is made
obvious by asking: what good is a sawmill without a forest?”
Then
in the subsequent sub-heading, Policy
Implications of the Turning Point,
these crucial points follow:
Pgs.
96/97
“Natural
capital productivity is increased by: (1) increasing the flow (net
growth) of natural resources per unit of natural stock (limited by
biological growth rates); (2) increasing product output per unit of
resource input (limited by mass balance); and especially by (3)
increasing the end-use efficiency with which the resulting product
yields services to the final user (limited by technology). We have
already argued that complementarity severely limits what we should
expect from (2), and complex ecological interrelations and the law of
conservation of matter-energy limits the increase from (1).
Therefore, the ecological economics focus should be mainly on (3).”
And
important qualification of these points appears a bit further into
this same sub-heading:
Pgs.
99/100
“Once
investments in natural capital have resulted in equilibrium stocks
that are maintained but not expanded (yielding a constant total
resource flow), then all further increases in economic welfare would
have to come from increases in pure efficiency resulting from
improvements in technology and clarification of priorities.
Certainly investments are being made in increasing biological growth
rates, and the advent of genetic engineering may add greatly to this
thrust. However, experience to date (e.g., the green revolution)
indicates that higher biological yield rates usually require the
sacrifice of some other useful quality (disease resistance, flavor,
strength of stalk). In any case, the law of conservation of
matter-energy cannot be evaded by genetics: more food from a plant or
animal implies either more inputs or less matter-energy going to the
non-food structures and functions of the organism (Cleveland 1994).
To carry the arguments for infrastructure investments into the area
of biophysical/environmental infrastructure or natural capital
replenishment will require new thinking by development economists.”
While
the allusion to genetic engineering in this last passage, and the
cautionary explanatory provisos associated with them, begin to
approach the greater nuance needed for properly understanding the
demanding and highly non-trivial set of implications gravitating
around the very important subject of tech-fixes, and whether the
techno-optimist hope that these will be sufficient in themselves to
‘save us’ ecologically is justified or not, the broader
technology horizon goes so far beyond the genetic examples given, and
so greatly further displaces the directness of the complementarity
between human-made capital and the natural capital resources which
may be its inputs, the need for clarification is not quite satisfied.
Much to the credit of this exceptionally good book, however, several
additional passages a bit further on take us in the right direction.
Sub-heading
3.3.2, tellingly entitled in the interrogative, Can
Built Capital Substitute for Natural Capital?,
starts:
“The
main issue is the relation between natural capital, which yields a
flow of natural resources and services that enter the process of
production, and the human-made capital that serves as an agent in the
process for transforming the resource inflow into a product outflow.
Is the flow of natural resources (and the stock of natural capital
that yields that flow) substitutable by human-made capital? Clearly,
one resource can substitute for another – we can transform aluminum
instead of copper into electric wire. . . . However, when we come to
substitution across the roles of transforming agent and material
undergoing transformation (efficient cause and material cause), the
possibilities of substitution become very limited and the
characteristic of complementarity is dominant.”
Deeply
incisive, important, and succinct as this passage otherwise is, the
final sentence falls victim to a major oversight relating to “the
possibilities of substitution”. At the scientific frontiers,
research and development is rife with the most profound implications
for “the main issue” which this passage correctly identifies.
But at that frontier, defining the category of “natural capital”
may require crucial modification at a much more fundamental level,
and going beyond reliance on the familiar, manifest flora and fauna
examples such as stocks of fish or timber referenced in this book.
The actual physical matter at this frontier – the material cause,
and in these cases generally comprised of elements from the periodic
table that are among the most basic and abundant on the planet –
presents not so much a case or instance of being transformed from the
manifestly macroscopic living state in which it may have been
embodied and preexisting as ‘natural capital’ in the raw state of
nature. At this frontier, it is matter at the atomic, molecular and
mesoscopic scales that is being composed by bottom-up accretion – a
blend of material, efficient and formal cause –rather than
transformed by means of bulk top-down subtractive milling, lathing,
grinding, stamping, etc. typical of conventionally understood
industrial capital instruments, to satisfy desired physical
properties; in many cases, properties which may not even exist in any
familiar macroscopic sources of ‘natural capital’, per se, at all
and are, therefore, beyond any prospectively viable top-down material
transformation at all; clearly a distinction much more than merely a
semantic quibble. And this is before even invoking the potential
compositional variations of biomimetic, synthetic biological and
related methods. Further, any thought that such capabilities are
limited to genetics, per se, would be, at this juncture in the
expanse of the R&D universe, virtually quaint; we are talking
material science, writ large; chemistry, biochemistry, lattice,
mesoscopic (and other) physics, photonics, metamaterials, de novo
protein, catalytic and enzymatic design, spintronic. plasmonic and
topological states of matter, certainly genetics, of course, and
others.
Perhaps
the ultimate hypothetical example of the intended distinction between
natural capital resource input transformation via conventionally
envisioned human-built industrial capital in the intuitive,
traditional sense which the characterizations in this book invoke, as
distinct from resource input composition, was articulated by K. Eric
Drexler in his now famous 1986 book, Engines
of Creation,
and his vision for molecular assemblers; i.e., distinguishing between
conventionally understood top-down machine/capital modification of
bulk matter into end products, versus the design of bottom-up atomic,
molecular and mesoscopic processes of composition into end processes
and/or products. And while the full realization of the kind of
actual molecular assemblers initially proposed, and repeatedly
clarified and justified by Dr. Drexler to be, in principle, perfectly
scientifically viable since 1986, remain on the R&D horizon, the
chorus of those inclined to dismiss their ultimate realization as
science fiction continues to dwindle in light of the kind of adjacent
advances represented by the work of the following very limited
sampling of researchers; some of which may complement and contribute
to what may well be multiple paths toward realizing Drexler’s
vision, and which has now become more generally known as atomically
precise manufacturing, or APM.
See:
-
Professor Omar Yaghi and Reticular Chemistry: https://pubs.acs.org/doi/10.1021/acscentsci.9b00750#
-
Professor Christian Schafmeister and Spiroligomers: https://www.schafmeistergroup.com/
-
Professor Frances Arnold and Evolutionary Protein Design: http://fhalab.caltech.edu/
-
Professor David Baker and Protein Design: https://www.bakerlab.org/
-
Professor Chad Mirkin and Nanomaterial Design: https://mirkin-group.northwestern.edu/people/chad-mirkin/
-
Professor Donald Ingber and Biologically Inspired Engineering: https://wyss.harvard.edu/
-
Professor Hao Yan and Molecular Design and Biomimetics: https://biodesign.asu.edu/molecular-design-and-biomimetics/
While
these transitional technologies, or even the eventual optimal
realization of the Drexler vision of APM, do not, of course, dissolve
mass balance or the conservation of matter-energy rightly emphasized
by ecological economists, what they are very likely to do is to
profoundly alter production process profiles with respect to a whole
raft of important considerations including: properly understanding
natural capital input substitutability, complementarity, degree of
complementarity, and specificity, with respect to an accurate
calculation of the Inada condition and Hicksian income, with respect
to diminished energy use, diminished waste stream generation,
increased circularity potential, with respect to gaining greater
clarity about when and where it is appropriate to extend the
depreciation concept to natural capital, and with respect to the
profuse efflorescent potential of end product variability and
differentiation. All of these and, of course, the crucial issue of
rebound effects, portend that the policy implications for ecological
economics may be extremely significant. How significant?
A
few pages after the last excerpt quoted above, the authors pose this
central and summary question: “To what extent can we substitute
manufactured for natural capital, and how much of our natural capital
is irreplaceable?” Well, in 2020, McKinsey & Company published
a report which sought to actually answer exactly the first of those
two questions.
(See: https://www.mckinsey.com/industries/life-sciences/our-insights/the-bio-revolution-innovations-transforming-economies-societies-and-our-lives?utm_source=pocket_saves
.)
Answer?
Even though the report is focused on only the biological and,
importantly, is not
inclusive of the range of other scientific domains just noted above
where comparable developments are occurring, their conclusion was,
“As
much as 60 percent of the physical inputs to the global economy”,
with “A
pipeline of about 400 use cases, almost all scientifically feasible
today,” which they designated as “already visible”. Clearly,
the long term opportunity for dramatically reducing the impacts
associated with considering answers for the second part of that dual
question may be stunning. And apparent corroboration of this
analytic assessment comes from what has begun to occur not merely in
the investor community - perhaps most aggressively exemplified by
Schmidt Ventures: https://www.schmidtfutures.com/our-work/task-force-on-synthetic-biology-and-the-bioeconomy/
- but also at the level of federal government policy evaluation.
These
considerations also suggest an additional, and very important
clarifying take-away demanding emphasis related to a passage
appearing a few pages further into this book.
(Page
131):
“But
natural capital is also very different from built capital. First of
all, built capital is made from natural capital. In other words,
nature can exist without built capital, but built capital cannot
exist without nature. There is an essential hierarchy limiting the
extent to which built capital can substitute for natural capital, and
they are better thought of as complements than substitutes.”
Since
those words were published not quite ten years ago, however, what has
become increasingly evident is that the degree of difference asserted
in this passage between the two forms of capital are being profoundly
blurred at the scientific and technological frontier, rendering the
salience of a continued insistence on a hard line of demarcation
increasingly problematic for informing policy. In other words, as
long as the mental model which ecological economics relies on
conceives of production processes strictly in terms whereby natural
capital inputs to human-built capital are defined only as top-down,
subtractive transformations from bulk objects of the natural world –
living or otherwise - into some finished form of output product, then
accurately defining the essential hierarchy just posited will be
misconstrued by missing the true, broader scientific and practical
significance of the revolutionary bottom-up compositional production
capabilities now becoming manifest. Getting this wrong puts at risk
the absolutely vital mission of getting ecological economics right,
so that its very important insights and broad prescriptions may
properly inform policies about what and where the real limits do
exist for input-output scenarios, for evaluation of, and
distinguishing between growth versus development scenarios and,
ultimately, for informing the conception of robust, adaptive
institutional forms needed to sustain true sustainability.
A
further step toward realizing that mission is also very well served
by an important recent paper by German economist, Stefan Mockel, of
the UFZ Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research, and published
through PLOS Sustainability and Transformation; see:
https://journals.plos.org/sustainabilitytransformation/article?id=10.1371/journal.pstr.0000095
In
the context of this webinar, the comments it has elicited here, and
as suggested in my previous blog written in support of the
Snower/Wilson paper seeking to redefine the foundations of economics
cited above, the importance of truly recognizing and confronting the
money-nature nexus addressed in this paper by Dr. Mockel could hardly
be overstated since there is likely no way of doing so that would not
entail deep institutional modification reflecting the kind of broad
integration which would transcend just economics, per se, precisely
because of the imperative that it be integrative systemically, in the
broader sense; in other words, in the parlance of the IPCC, “it is
clear now that minor, marginal, reactive or incremental changes won’t
be sufficient.” Another perspective on the importance of this
money-nature nexus theme was offered by noted, indeed, perhaps the
‘father’ of modern ecological economics, Herman Daly, in the
following 2013 essay in which he asked and answered the question, ‘is
there a better way’.
(See: https://steadystate.org/nationalize-money-not-banks/?utm_source=pocket_saves
)
Perhaps
analogous to the politically fatal ‘third rail’ danger often
ascribed to any proposal perceived to subject the Social Security
program in the U.S. to existential jeopardy, the conspicuous and
nearly total policy silence which wreaths this subject in spite of
how deeply fulcral it is to truly systemic change, may well be a
tacit, subliminal admission of political and administrative terror at
the prospect of taking on something so fundamental; in effect, of
daring to venture into theoretical and institutional territory
presumed reminiscent of medieval oceanic maps demarcating horizon
boundaries beyond which all that could be said is that here ‘there
be dragons’. And what be the ‘dragons’ beyond this conceptual
and institutional horizon? Any such truly systemically integrated
money-nature-nexus institutional modifications that are inclusive of
the defining criteria and metrics of ecological economics will, if
history and hierarchy theory is any guide, almost certainly compel
corollary revisions to legal criteria defining corporate charters and
incentives, with obvious implications for the nature of anti-trust
and other related administrative regulatory issues explored by Ms.
Hearn and professor Wilson in this webinar; in effect, a stirring of
the hornets nest of imminent political and incumbent commercial power
plays over whose ‘ox’ is likely to be gored by taking seriously
the need to institutionally embody truly systemic
operational economic/ financial/monetary criteria consistent with the
multi-level selection theory imperative to make the conscious unit of
selection at the global level. If so, again, Ms. Hearn’s
invocation of the term ‘profound’ during her talk seems highly
appropriate; not least because – whether correct or not – what
seems implied may be perceived as tantamount to the proverbial case
of building a new supersonic airliner while in mid-flight.
And
holding that analogy in mind may provide the ideal segue for circling
back to the aspiration expressed at the outset of these comments to
conclude by venturing some suggestions for what might be ‘next
steps’ worthy of serious consideration by Human Energy and the
Evolution Institute as a sustained follow-on initiative to the recent
inaugural Noosphere Masterclass.
Whatever
else realizing an inspired and dynamically positive Noosphere may
entail in ascending toward the upper tiers of the Maslow hierarchy,
certainly one very fundamental sine qua non requirement will be the
kind of systemic integration of ecological economics into our global
institutional forms and governance processes just suggested. Where
and how doing this overlaps with precisely the broader palette of
higher social factors implicated in the emerging Noosphere suggests a
most compelling ‘next steps’ opportunity for Human Energy and the
Evolution Institute. Specifically, ecological economics is also
deeply implicated in the growing consideration being given globally
to alternatives to GDP as an indicator of a.) economic welfare, and
more broadly, b.) human well being and total human welfare; a theme
which even the introductory text on the subject cited at some length
several times above goes on to devote considerable space to
developing and illuminating. And as a complement, this recent
YouTube presentation both corroborates its significance, provides a
sense of some of the UN and other participants, and offers a glimmer
of how much room remains for solution proposals which expand the
scope of transdisciplinarity on the basis of which to provide them.
(See: https://www.youtube.com/live/0ZP6Dr4POEo?si=HzJDQ0TUg26fWjuZ
)
In
short, there is a very strong case to be made that there may be few,
if any, better ways to serve facilitating the instantiation of the
foundational conditions required for a Noosphere of mutually
reinforcing virtuous cycles than this.
As
such, Human Energy and the Evolution Institute would be providing an
invaluable public service to consider jointly sponsoring, organizing
and mediating recurring conferences – perhaps annually or
bi-annually – with invited guests representing a highly
transdisciplinary array of expertise to generally explore a.) most
effective paths for such systemic integration and, more specifically,
b.) needed institutional innovations to embody these. The
‘deliverable’ objective of the conferences would be summary
guides meant to inform both policy makers and the wider public. And
perhaps most importantly, this would offer an ideal venue to
incorporate something which receives far too little consideration,
but which was a key point of emphasis in this very important recent
paper by Anders Sandberg (Oxford Univ.) and co-author, Len Fisher: A
Safe Governance Space for Humanity: Necessary Conditions for the
Governance of Global Catastrophic Risks.
(See:
chrome-extension://efaidnbmnnnibpcajpcglclefindmkaj/https://ora.ox.ac.uk/objects/uuid:ada8806a-c6de-4807-9683-06f3d4d06f5d/files/r2227mq26s
)
While
there is a great deal in this paper to recommend attention and
justify elaborating or qualifying comment – perhaps especially the
cautionary references to the influence of reflexivity – emphasizing
the process nature of the three enabling conditions to “facilitate
transition to the new form of governance” cited in the paper’s
Conclusions would be highly justified for inclusion in the
exploration agenda of the kind of conferences being suggested. And
of these three, the first - “‘bridging organisations’ to
connect governance levels and spatial and temporal scales” –
might be the most crucial. Why?
Throughout
these comments, repeated reference has been made to what is,
effectively (if tacitly), an institutionally embodied categorical
political priority and operational deference accorded by State power
to an economic/financial/monetary system which ‘bakes in’ a
socioeconomic dependence on perpetual growth. The fact that this
deference has persisted for over four hundred years, the fact that it
continues to persist in contravention of the sobering reality, voiced
with increasingly confident scientific warnings, that we are now
confronted with existential threats directly related to the
compounding feedback impacts arising from the diffuse and myriad
systemic tentacles which embody this deference, is reflective of the
absence of precisely something like ‘bridging organizations’; in
this context, particularly the absence of a meta-organization which
would serve the function of on-going oversight of the prevailing
institutional infrastructure to assess whether it remains consistent
with the broad public interest in planetary sustainability. Indeed,
merely pointing out such an absence with the suggestion that this
constitutes a serious flaw in the system of governance might seem, at
least, surprising and, perhaps, heretical. Given this, it is worth
briefly pausing here to interject two passages from the book, Digital
Disconnect,
by professor Robert. W. McChesney, that could scarcely be more on
point.
In
the first he notes: “C.B.
Macpherson was among the first to grasp how a duopolistic party
system in a modern capitalist society like the United States will
tend to provide a “competition between elites”, which “formulate
the issues”. The
basics of the political economy are agreed upon by the two parties
and are off the table for public debate or discussion.”
(Emphasis added.) In the second, emphasizing a key responsibility
of the journalistic Fourth Estate deeply relevant to our next point,
he observes: “Such journalism addresses not only the transitory
concerns of the moment, but also challenges that loom on the horizon.
It must translate important scientific issues accurately into lay
language. These
issues cannot be determined primarily by what people in power are
talking about.
(Emphasis added.) Journalism must provide the nation’s early
warning system, so problems can be anticipated, studied, debated, and
addressed before they grow to crisis proportions.”
Not
only do these passages – and especially those in bold/italic
emphasis – highlight why our current governance structures are so
problematic precisely for their absence of such a meta-organizational
oversight function, and for the blind, relentless momentum of the
economic status quo that it locks us into, but they also beg this
question. Does history provide any guidance or examples where such
oversight was not absent? Fortunately, though few may be aware of it
- and with thanks, yet again, to ancient Greece - there is a relevant
precedent.
In
striving to decisively debunk the fallacious but common misconception
that ancient Athenian democracy was a form of direct citizen – as
opposed to representative – democracy, Yale University political
science professor, Helene Landemore, offers this clarification in her
very valuable book, Open
Democracy: Reinventing Popular Rule for the Twenty-First Century:
“The
main legislative institutions of Classical Athens were the Boule, or
Council of 500; the Ekklesia, the People’s Assembly; the
Nomothetai; and (in the fourth century BC) even the courts. The
Council was a body of 500 citizens randomly selected among the
willing and able. It was “a
linchpin institution that was given control of the vital agenda
setting function for the meetings of the People’s Assembly”
(Ober 2008, 142; emphasis added) . . . The People’s Assembly, by
contrast, was an open Assembly where up to 8000 citizens were able to
gather in order to deliberate and vote about the Council’s
proposals.
“Assuming
for now that the People’s Assembly can legitimately count as an
institution of direct democracy, this
assembly was thus largely dependent on agenda-setting by the Council
of 500.
According to Josiah Ober, the
institution of the randomly selected council was in fact the key
institution in Greek democracy and may even have been more central to
the Greek’s concept of democracy than the Assembly
(Ober 1997 and 2008; emphasis added).”
In
light of such a compelling precedent, of governance structures
designed to invest the fundamental agenda-setting (oversight)
function in the hands of the people, and so carefully conceived to do
so in a truly democratic manner, perhaps what should now seem
surprising, or even heretical, are current structures where such a
function is either absent or where the system is left
undemocratically in a position of decision dependence only on “what
people in power are talking about”; dependence on a “
“competition
between elites”, which “formulate the issues”, and where “The
basics of the political economy are agreed upon by the two parties
and are off the table for public debate or discussion.” In
contrast, with
the Athenian Boule, in principle, there is conceptually clearly no
reason that “the basics of the political economy” would be
precluded from being very much on
the table “for public debate or discussion” if conditions emerged
which might make this appropriate for evaluation. This is obviously
what it means to be authentically in the service of the broader
public interest, as opposed to merely serving the interests reflected
in “what people in power are talking about”.
Returning
to the present, exploring whether there are, indeed, emergent
conditions which might justify placing exactly such
meta-institutional evaluation center stage for purposes of “public
debate or discussion”, presents an embarrassment of riches. Just
two examples closely related to the dynamics of the money-nature
nexus problem, and having quite profound policy and institutional
implications, are presented in the following recent and very
important papers:
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0921800923003130
https://www.nature.com/articles/ncomms14389
In
light of a multitude of revelations about major commercial/oil
interests having concealed and purposefully lied for decades about
their knowledge of the virtually inevitable ecological consequences
from continued use of fossil fuels, of revelations about how these
same interests opened the funding spigots for Congressional lobbying
to purchase inertia and inaction, often predicated on the
phony-science propaganda output of bogus think tank front groups, it
seems far from wild speculation to imagine that impartial citizens
comprising a modern instantiation of the agenda-setting function
provided by the Athenian Boule would assess the broader public
interest implications of papers such as these, and what policy and/or
institutional restructuring response those interests might warrant
serious evaluation of, very differently than our existing
‘democratic’ institutions are willing or equipped to provide;
especially since the chances are unfortunately far beyond remote that
papers of such substance and moment as these would ever receive
“public debate or discussion” by our current severely compromised
institutions to begin with. Hence, the great potential value of the
conferences being suggested here. These would have the effect of
serving notice to politicians of dubious devotion to the real public
interest, that the public is increasingly ‘wise’ to what is being
kept “off
the table for public debate or discussion”;
including the “basics
of the political economy”,
as well as the very structural design of our governance institutions;
neither of which warrants any default deference to be held as
sacrosanct and beyond possible modification if the true
governance objective is service to what is the ultimate broader
public interest of living sustainably within scientifically defined
planetary boundaries. But they might also have the more affirmative
salutary effective of inspiring more people of higher calling and
sense of public service to seek representative office, and amplify a
broader public zeitgeist where more of the citizenry would
enthusiastically embrace opportunities to participate in deliberative
democratic fora as these continue to become more and more pervasive.
But the latter hopeful prospect also raises an important point.
First, the spirit of precisely such a zeitgeist is already evident in
the proliferation of countless grassroots efforts to exercise
constructive agency by citizens all over the world. It would,
however, be an error to infer that the groundswell of these important
and necessary public actions constitute a sufficient substitute for
structurally and conceptually deep institutional innovations which
would further facilitate their ultimate success.
To
readers for whom such considerations renew frustrations and
disappointments with the United Nations for failing to provide
precisely the kind of visionary meta-organizational evaluation being
suggested here for Human Energy and the Evolution Institute, there is
actually hopeful news. The following links introduce the scheduled
U.N. Summit of the Future, scheduled for September, 2024. And
similar to the suggestion here that the proposed Human
Energy/Evolution Institute conferences be recurring, as the following
Carnegie Endowment discussion specifies, this U.N. initiative is not
intended to be a single, one-off event; something which, it could be
strongly argued, could present recurring Human Energy/Evolution
Institute conferences of the type proposed here with a serious
opportunity to be a complementary, or perhaps even a guiding resource
for and partner with the Summit(s) of the Future.
https://www.youtube.com/live/T1s2qgM_kx0?si=kgRW6uaTYcg852sH
https://www.un.org/en/common-agenda/summit-of-the-future
That
said, this may be the most propitious point to conclude these
comments.
Before
doing so by invoking several concluding passages from the excellent
book, An
Introduction to Ecological Economics,
cited several times above, offering a few suggestions for conference
attendees whose expertise might otherwise be overlooked may be
constructive. Though perhaps understood, all of the authors,
scientists and scholars already cited in these comments would be high
priority choices. Further, clearly the extensive personal and
professional networks of most of the key founders and advisors with
Human Energy and the Evolution Institute, will be a rich source of
attendee expert candidates.
- Economist
Steve Keen.
Professor Keen has long been an incisive, vociferous and even
ruthless critic of the deeply flawed logic and dangers of
Neoclassical economics. A major reason for his sense of urgency and
mission may be best intimated with this passage from his recent book, The
New Economics: A Manifesto:
“I can say only one thing in favor of the work by Neoclassical
economists on climate change: it is so bad that, once it becomes
obvious how serious a threat climate change is, revulsion at how
Neoclassical economists have trivialized the dangers may finally lead
to the overthrow of Neoclassical economics itself.” Then, as
synopsis of his more general critique of the Neoclassical paradigm,
he observes: “That, in essence, is the Neoclassical disease:
treating something that any outside observer would regard as a
fantasy as a ‘simplifying assumption’, and asserting that the
fantasy cannot be questioned when one challenges the resulting model.
Economics abounds in such fantastical assumptions because of the
problem outlined in the first chapter: economics has, time and time
again, been subject to paradigm-challenging anomalies, but rather
than accepting the challenge, economists have responded by making
ridiculous assumptions to shield the paradigm from criticism.”
- Robert
Ashford, Syracuse University professor of Corporate Law.
Professor Ashford’s mastery of the theoretically distinctive
conceptual foundations of binary economics, and their profound
implications for rationalizing the design of institutions with the
real promise, over time, of universalizing citizen ownership of
productive capital assets without recourse to either transfer-state
redistribution schemes or confiscatory tax or other claims on
existing asset owners, is unparalleled. His insights and
understanding also have profound implications for resolving the
challenge of how to finance the transition to a ‘green’ capital
base; something presenting almost insuperable difficulties under the
ownership-concentrating ‘rules of the game’ of conventional
finance.
- Poe
Yu-Ze Wan, Sociology professor at the National Sun Yat-sen
University, Taiwan.
Why his participation would be recommended will likely be
self-evident with even a cursory review of his important paper, Systems
Theory: Irredeemably Holistic and Antithetical to Planning?,
and related book, Reframing
the Social: Emergentist Systemism and Social Theory.
- Andrew
W. Lo, MIT professor of Finance.
Beyond mere expertise in finance, the creative and innovative
accomplishments of professor Lo in developing the Adaptive Markets
Hypothesis, and its potential relevance if/when applied in a context
of institutional innovation to enable ecological economics, should
perhaps most recommend his invitation to participate. https://mitsloan.mit.edu/faculty/directory/andrew-w-lo
- J.
Doyne Farmer.
Leading complexity theorist and researcher, formerly with the Santa
Fe Institute, founding entrepreneur with the Prediction Company, and
currently at Oxford University, the April 2024 release of his new
book, Making
Sense of Chaos: A Better Economics for a Better World,
promises to be a very substantive addition to the literature. https://www.doynefarmer.com/book
- Alex
Pentland,
MIT
Computer/Data Scientist
with a long resume of innovation and extensive affiliations; perhaps
most importantly in this context, as a Board member with the U.N.
Foundations’ Global Partnership for Sustainable Development.
- Thomas
Homer-Dixon, founding Director of The Cascade Institute
and author with extensive expertise in system-dynamics modes of
analysis. As stated here - https://cascadeinstitute.org/
- the mission of Mr. Homer-Dixon and this Institute could scarcely be
more ideally suited to the objective of the conferences proposed
here.
- Mariana
Mazzucato, economist and founding Director of the UCL Institute for
Innovation and Public Purpose. https://marianamazzucato.com/
Professor Mazzucato’s important work debunking the misapprehension
that entrepreneurial value creation and the State are inherently
mutually exclusive, that social and economic policy are dramatically
improved when the economic system is understood to have both an
extent and a direction, and her extensive experience in advising
policy makers on both – often in a context coupled with
institutional innovation - would be invaluable in the kind of
conferences being proposed here.
IN
CONCLUSION:
Given
the purpose of these comments stated at the outset, the choice to
conclude with the additional passages below from the book cited
several times earlier, An
Introduction to Ecological Economics,
will
likely be quickly evident. The choice is then reinforced with the
prospect of possible collaboration between the proposed Human Energy/
Evolution Institute conferences with the U.N. Summit of the Future.
And this very recent paper published in PLOS
Sustainability and Transformation
may be considered a useful complement:
https://journals.plos.org/sustainabilitytransformation/article?id=10.1371/journal.pstr.0000098
-
pg. 76: “The co-evolutionary perspective helps us see that the
problem of humans interacting with their environment is not simply a
matter of establishing market incentives or appropriate rules about
the use of property. Our values, knowledge, and social organization
have co-evolved around fossil hydrocarbons. Our fossil fuel-driven
economy has not simply transformed the environment, it has selected
for individualist, materialist values, favored the development of
reductionist understanding at the expense of systemic understanding,
and preferred a bureaucratic, centralized form of control that works
better for steady-state industrial management than for the varied,
surprising dynamics of ecosystem management. And the co-evolutionary
framing highlights how our abilities to perceive and resolve
environmental problems within the dominant modes of valuing,
thinking, and organizing are severely constrained.”
-
pg. 88
“The
transdisciplinary view provides an overarching coherence that can tie
disciplinary knowledge together and that can address the increasingly
important problems that cannot be addressed within the disciplinary
structure. In this sense, ecological economics is not an alternative
to any of the existing disciplines. Rather it is a new way of
looking at the problem that can add value to the existing approaches
and that can address some of the deficiencies of the disciplinary
approach. It is not a question of “conventional economics”
versus “ecological economics” but rather conventional economics
as one input (among many) to a broader transdisciplinary synthesis.
“We
believe that this transdisciplinary way of looking at the world is
essential if we are to achieve the three interdependent goals of
ecological economics discussed here: sustainable scale, fair
distribution, and efficient allocation. This requires the
integration of three elements: (1) a practical, shared vision of the
way the world works and of the sustainable society we wish to
achieve; (2) methods of analysis and modeling that are relevant to
the new questions and problems this vision embodies, and (3) new
institutions and instruments that can effectively use the analyses to
adequately implement the vision.
“The
importance of the integration of these three components cannot be
overstated. Too often when discussing practical applications, we
focus only on the implementation element, forgetting that an adequate
vision of the world and our goals is often the most practical device
for achieving the vision, and that without appropriate methods of
analysis even the best vision can be blinded. The importance of
communication and education concerning all three elements also cannot
be overstated.
“The
basic points of consensus in the ecological economics vision are as
follows:
1.)
The vision of the Earth as a thermodynamically closed and
non-materially growing system, with the human economy as a subsystem
of the global ecosystem. This implies that there are limits to
biophysical throughput of resources from the ecosystem, through
economic subsystem, and back to the ecosystem as wastes.
2.)
The future vision of a sustainable planet with a high quality of life
for all its citizens (humans and other species) within the material
constraints imposed by 1.
3.)
The recognition that in the analysis of complex systems such as the
Earth at all space and time scales, fundamental uncertainty is large
and irreducible and certain processes are irreversible, requiring a
fundamentally precautionary stance.
4.)
That institutions and management should be proactive rather than
reactive and should result in simple, adaptive, and implementable
policies based on a sophisticated understanding of the underlying
systems that fully acknowledge the underlying uncertainties. This
forms the basis for policy implementation, which is itself
sustainable.
5.)
The last point is conceptually pluralistic. This means that even
while people writing in ecological economics were trained in a
particular discipline (and may prefer that mode of thinking over
others), they are open to an appreciation of other modes of thinking
and actively seek a constructive dialogue among disciplines (Norgaard
1989). There is not one right approach or model because, like the
blind men and the elephant, the subject is just too big and complex
to touch all of it with one limited set of perceptual or
computational tools.”
Page
91:
“Priority
of Problems.
The problems of efficient allocation, fair distribution, and
sustainable scale are highly interrelated but distinct; they are most
effectively solved in a particular priority order, and they are best
solved with independent policy instruments (Daly 1992). There are an
infinite number of efficient allocations but only one for each
distribution and scale. Allocative efficiency does not guarantee
sustainability (Bishop 1993). It is clear that scale should not be
determined by prices but by a social decision reflecting ecological
limits. Distribution should not be determined by prices but by a
social decision reflecting a just distribution of assets. Subject to
these social decisions, individualistic trading in the market is then
able to allocate the scarce rights efficiently. . . .
“The
prices that measure the opportunity costs of reallocation are
unrelated to measures of the opportunity costs of redistribution or
of a change in scale. Any trade-off among the three goals (e.g., an
improvement in distribution in exchange for a worsening in scale or
allocation, or more unequal distribution in exchange for sharper
incentives seen as instrumental to more efficient allocation)
involves an ethical judgment about the quality of our social
relations rather than a willingness-to-pay calculation. The contrary
view, that this choice among basic social goals and the quality of
social relations that help to define us as persons should be made on
the basis of individual willingness-to-pay, just as the trade-off
between chewing gum and shoelaces is made, seems to be dominant in
economics today, and it is part of the retrograde modern reduction of
all ethical choices to the level of personal tastes weighted by
income.
“It
is instructive to consider the historical attempt of the scholastic
economists to subsume distribution under allocation (or more likely
they were subsuming allocation under distribution – at any rate
they did not make the distinction). This was the famous “just
price” doctrine of the Middle Ages that has been totally rejected
in economic theory, although it stubbornly survives in the politics
of minimum wages, farm price supports, water and electric power
subsidies, and so forth. However, we do not, as a general rule, try
to internalize the external cost of distributive injustice into
market prices. We reject the attempt to correct market prices for
their unwanted effects on income distribution. Economists nowadays
keep allocation and distribution quite separate, and they argue for
letting prices serve only efficiency, while serving justice with the
separate policy of transfers. This follows Tinbergen’s dictum of
equality of policy goals and instruments: one instrument for each
policy. The point is that just as we cannot subsume distribution
under allocation, neither can we subsume scale under allocation.
“It seems clear, then, that we need to address the problems
in the following order: first, establish the ecological limits of
sustainable scale and establish policies that assure that the
throughput of the economy stays within these limits. Second,
establish a fair and just distribution of resources using systems of
property right and transfers. The property right systems can cover
the full spectrum from individual to government ownership, but
intermediate systems of common ownership and systems for dividing the
ownership of resources into ownership of particular services need
much more attention (Young 1992). Third, once the scale and
distribution problems are solved, market-based mechanisms can be used
to allocate resources efficiently. This involves extending the
existing market to internalize the many environmental goods and
services that are currently outside the market.”
-
pg. 7: “Since the Club of Rome’s 1972 “Limits to Growth,” the
emphasis has shifted from source limits to sink limits. Source
limits are more open to substitution, are more amenable to private
ownership, and are more localized. Consequently, they are more
amenable to control by markets and prices. Sink limits involve
common property where markets fail. Since 1972, the case has
substantially strengthened so that there are limits to throughput
growth on the sink side (Meadows et al. 1992; Randers 2012). Some of
these limits are tractable and are being tackled, such as the CFC
(chlorofluorocarbon) phaseout under the Montreal Convention. Other
limits are less tractable, such as increasing CO2 emissions and the
massive human appropriation of biomass. Another example is landfill
sites, which are becoming extremely difficult to find. Garbage is
now shipped thousands of miles from industrial to developing
countries in search of unfilled sinks. It has so far proved
impossible for the U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission to rent a
nuclear waste site.”
-
pgs. 50: “To bring a system into equilibrium, negative feedbacks
are needed. Economics helps us see how biodiversity is decreasing
because so few genetic traits, species, or ecosystems have market
prices, the negative feedback signals that equilibrate market
economies. In market systems, prices increase to reduce the quantity
demanded when supplies are low and prices drop to increase the
quantity demanded when supplies are high, keeping demand and supply
in equilibrium. The problem, economists argue, is that most genetic
traits, species, and ecosystems are being lost because they do not
have prices acting as a negative feedback system to keep use in
equilibrium with availability. When individuals of the species become
fewer, increasing price to decrease quantity is not an option. By
putting economic values on species and including them in market
signals through various ways would reduce biodiversity loss.
Furthermore, the economic explanation and solution is systemic. . . .
“Biologists
also find the idea that we need to know the economic values of
species compatible with their own understanding that if the true
value of species to society were understood, more species would be
conserved. Clearly, if we knew the value of biological resources, we
would be in a better position to manage them more effectively. And,
to the extent these values could be included in the market system,
markets themselves could assist in the conservation of biodiversity.
The situation can frequently be improved through amending market
signals. At the same time, it is important to remember that market
values only exist within a larger system of values, which for many
people include the preservation of nature for ethical or religious
reasons (Sagoff 1988).”
-
pg. 51: “Although several techniques for estimating the value of
the environment are proving interesting, valuation is by no means an
easy task and estimates should be used cautiously. A major
difficulty is related to the systemic nature of economics,
ecosystems, and the process of environmental degradation. Market
systems relate everything to everything else. For example, when the
price of oil changes, it causes the price of gasoline to change,
which causes the demand and hence the price of products that use
gasoline, such as automobiles, to change, which causes the demand for
and hence the price of coal to change, and so on. Prices bring
markets to equilibrium and their flexibility is essential to this
task. Similarly, the “right” price for a given species or
ecosystem will depend on the availability of a host of other species
or ecosystems with which they are interdependent as well as with
other species and ecosystems that may be substitutes or complements
in use. To think that a species or ecosystem has a single value is
to deny ecosystem and economic system interconnections.
Nevertheless, environmental valuation can assist us in understanding
at least the minimal importance of ecological services and in
conveying this understanding to the public to improve the political
process of finding common ground.”